idiosyncraticwhisk.blogspot.com 2017 |
idiosyncraticwhisk.blogspot.com 2017 |
This pattern of Price/Rent ratios exists in every MSA. Given that, and comparing White House tax numbers with BEA imputed rental income numbers (income tax benefits amount to about 25% of net rental yields after consumption of capital, and most of those benefits are claimed by high income households) we can infer that, at the low end of the market, dominated by landlord owners and by households with little in tax obligations, tax benefits are negligible. At the high end of the market, the marginal tax benefit must top out at something well above 30% of the value of net rental yield.
In 2006, low end Price/Rent levels appear to generally run about 30%-40% below P/R at the high end, across cities. Every city has a different peak Price/Rent level, depending on rent inflation expectations, property tax rates, etc. But, they all have this pattern. (Low end prices are currently more depressed than normal because of unusual credit constraints.)
But, it appears that at something around $500,000, the marginal tax benefit and the average tax benefit of any further increases in home value are about the same. Above that level, P/R flattens out. So, for cities where home prices rise above that level, this positive feedback loop in rising prices ceases. It isn't that low priced homes in Closed Access cities were rising unusually during the bubble. It's that their high end homes weren't rising as sharply as they would normally rise in a similar environment because their Price/Rent ratios were no longer expanding.
idiosyncraticwhisk.blogspot.com 2017 |
idiosyncraticwhisk.blogspot.com 2017 |
idiosyncraticwhisk.blogspot.com 2017 |
This pattern is quite regular.
Notice also what we see here. In the cities where low end prices
idiosyncraticwhisk.blogspot.com 2017 |
idiosyncraticwhisk.blogspot.com 2017 |
So, there are two distinct reasons for the exceptional decline in low priced homes during the bust. The initial decline in 2007 and early 2008 was specific to the Closed Access cities and was simply an unwinding of this tax effect. Again, it isn't so much that the low tier homes were falling faster in those cities, as it is that the high tier homes had more moderate price shifts because they didn't have this pro-cyclical feedback. Notice how level the high quintile prices were in San Francisco and LA during the bust compared to the other cities listed here.
idiosyncraticwhisk.blogspot.com 2017 |
Notice that the lower tier collapse isn't as noticeable in the Closed Access cities as it is in the other cities during this later period. That is because these effects are now mitigating. All cities are affected by the severe constraints in low tier mortgage markets. But, in the Closed Access cities, as prices rise again, the positive feedback of P/R would be pushing those low priced homes up at a faster rate if it wasn't fighting those constraints.
I find that even I tend to make demand-side inferences that I eventually have to backtrack on when I realize that markets are more efficient and intrinsic value is more important than I gave them credit for. When I originally questioned the credit-supply explanation for this effect, I inferred from the pattern that it was the migration flows into and out of the Closed Access cities that created this effect. I inferred that the marginal home buyers had higher incomes than previous owners, so that they could capture more of these benefits, and that had something to do with the sharper rates of appreciation in lower priced neighborhoods.
But, I was wrong. Intrinsic value rules the day, in the end. In the aggregate, housing markets appear to be even more efficient than I tended to assume. There is ample inter-tier substitution throughout local housing markets. In hindsight, it is implausible that some portions of a metropolitan market would have unsustainably high valuations because of demand-side factors. (By this, I mean factors such as credit supply. Real estate will always be dominated by local factors that are related to changings rent levels due to localized market shifts in amenities, safety, etc.) In the aggregate, where those local valuation factors tend to average out, we can see that tax benefits are priced into home values quite systematically and the potency of credit supply as an explanation appears to be limited to the extreme case, where severe constraints prevent prices from rising to their intrinsic values. (Or, stated from a different framing, the retrenchment of the owner-occupier market farther up into mid-tier markets pulls prices in those markets down to the landlord level, where owner-occupier tax benefits are not available. So, the slope of the P/R relationship is now steeper.)
I suppose if I have changed my mind before, I might end up changing it again. But, so far, the changes induced by my exposure to the data have been changes toward more respect for macro-efficiency.
Great post.
ReplyDeleteI am not sure what it means, if anything, but it turns out in Australia there is no home mortgage interest tax deduction on home loans, and the loans are recourse loans (!).
Canada has no home-mortgage interest tax deduction either.
Aussie still has a huge (yuuge) house price run-up. Canada too.
Interesting. Thanks, Benjamin.
DeleteThank you for sharing such great information. It is informative, can you help me in finding out more detail on home loan tax benefit.
ReplyDelete