(This post takes as its jumping off point the market monetarist point of view that monetary policy has been too tight since 2007, and that, because of this, stock market returns and interest rates have been positively correlated during that time, as periods of looser monetary policy have resulted in higher inflation expectations and real economic growth expectations.)
I think what may have been missing from simple models of the nominal
interest rate is an inflation uncertainty factor. When we compare TIPS and nominal bonds, we
can get a basic idea of real rates & inflation expectations. But, because of the uncertainty around the
Fed’s expanded balance sheet and duration risk, even if expected inflation is
typical, there is probably a much larger range of possible inflation outcomes
than usual. The effect of this
uncertainty should be threefold:
1)
TIPS bonds would fetch a premium above the level
produced by average inflation expectations alone. This would create the illusion of lower real
rates and higher expected inflation when comparing TIPS to nominal rates.
2)
Because this is a risk premium, the premium
would be shared by both TIPS and nominal bonds.
In other words, as TIPS are bid up, some investors will choose to
purchase nominal bonds because they will be willing to take on inflation
uncertainty in order to capture some of the premium from #1.
3)
The net effect will be to lower yields in
general because concerns about future Fed errors related to the management of
the balance sheet lower average expectations about future economic growth. In summary, the inflation yield will look
higher and the real yield will look lower, in equal amounts, plus there will be
an additional downward effect on the actual real yield due to the uncertainty
itself.
So,
how does this help to understand recent market movements?
First,
what exactly happened in the yield curve?
I have a model that uses Eurodollar futures to derive the expected date
of the first rate increase, the quarterly rate of subsequent rate increases,
and the level of uncertainty around the timing of the first increase. This model shows two distinct periods of
activity:
1)
From the end of April to mid-June, rising
forward rates suggest a movement in the first rate increase from late 2015 to
late 2014. This presumably was the
product of improving expectations about the economy, which could be from a
mixture of expectations of Fed accommodation and empirically improving macro
data.
2)
After mid-June, the expected date of the rate
increase remained around the end of 2014.
What changed was an increase in the slope of the forward yield curve,
and a decrease in the uncertainty around the timing of the first rate increase
(first around June 13, but then especially around the Fed meeting on June
18-19). Without getting into the nuts
& bolts of the model, in the graph below, you can see how the second period
of change comes from a sharper convexity around the expected rate increase and
a steeper slope for the later dates, whereas the June 11 curve is basically the
May 1 curve moved back 1 year in time.
My speculation is that the May & early June rate increases are easily explained by improved economic expectations. And the late June interest rate movement did not come from Fed tightening. In fact, the stationary expected date of the rate change suggests that the market did not see any net change in the Fed’s monetary stance. I think the largest effect was the clarification of the winding down of QE3, which decreased the inflation uncertainty factor discussed above. The market’s marginal expectations about inflation and Fed OMO have not changed, but the market is much more confident about it, and is less worried about a premature or late exit from QE3. What effects would we expect this change to have?
1) Apparent
real rates in the TIPS market would go up.
2) Apparent
inflation expectations would go down.
3) Actual
real rates would go up, as confidence about managed economic expansion increases,
raising nominal rates.
4) And
we can add one further expectation:
Stock performance has been positively correlated with rising rates since
2008, which is a sign that monetary policy has been too tight. Why, then, did the S&P 500 dip on June 19
at the same time that interest rates jumped?
If we take this uncertainty factor into account, we would expect that
there would be two factors affecting the stock market. (1) a bullish effect from increased certainty
about the end of QE3 and (2) a bearish effect from the decrease in the
inflation uncertainty premium, since stocks can serve as an inflation hedge. The net effect would be indeterminate, but
could be slightly bearish, which is what we saw.
I don’t have a systematic way of measuring
this uncertainty effect, but for the purpose of visualizing it, I have manually
created an estimate of the effect based on the quantity of Fed holdings, the
increase in duration during Operation Twist, and gradual improvement as
positive economic news came in over 2013, with a one time positive shock at the
Fed announcement on June 19. This is
admittedly ad hoc and unscientific.
The dotted lines below represent the typical
Real Rate & Inflation component derived from TIPS and nominal rates. The solid lines include my imprecise
uncertainty effect and the inflation and real components once they have been
adjusted for the distortions of this effect on TIPS yields. Whether or not the scale of the effect is
accurate, as graphed, the basic idea remains that the actual effect of the QEs
on inflation expectations has probably been decreasing over time, relative to
the effect suggested by the TIPS spread; the effect of the QEs on the real rate
has been stronger than suspected, but has had to fight the increasing
uncertainty premium until recent economic optimism led to a bottoming of this
effect; and the recent reactions of interest rates and stock prices to Fed
clarifications setting more precise limits on QE3 could have resulted from a relatively small pulse change
in this effect, not from changes in the real rate or inflation expectations.
what is cloud computing - Cloud Computing Models · Infrastructure as a Service (IaaS) · Platform as a Service (PaaS) Software as a Service (SaaS). Learn types of cloud computing. For more visit thewebseeker
ReplyDeleteThis article will be beneficial to those who are studying economics. Many students are concerned about their upcoming university assignments. They were concerned since they were not focusing on their studies. Students should get knowledge that will assist them in completing their tasks. A company in the United Kingdom offers students cheap assignment writing services. Students can obtain high grades with their assistance.
ReplyDelete